The hyperinflation
in the Weimar Republic
was a three-year period of hyperinflation in the Weimar
Republic (modern-day Germany )
between June 1921 and January 1924.
Background
In order to pay the large costs of the First World War,
German currency was relatively stable at about 90 Marks per US Dollar during the first half of 1921. Because the Western theatre warfare was mostly in
The first payment was made when due in June 1921. That was the beginning of an increasingly rapid devaluation of the Mark which fell to less than one third of a cent by November 1921 (approx. 330 Marks per US Dollar). The total reparations demanded was 132,000,000,000 (132 billion) gold marks, of which
Because reparations were required to be repaid in hard currency and not the rapidly depreciating Papiermark, one strategy
Hyperinflation
Beginning in August 1921,
During the first half of 1922, the Mark stabilized at about 320 Marks per Dollar. This was accompanied by international reparations conferences, including one in June 1922 organized by
In January 1923 French and Belgian troops occupied the Ruhr, the industrial region of
By November 1923, the American dollar was worth 4,210,500,000,000 German marks.
As a result of hyperinflation, there were news accounts of individuals in
Stabilization
When a new
currency, the Rentenmark, replaced the worthless Reichsbank marks on November
16, 1923 and 12 zeros were cut from prices, prices in the new currency remained
stable. The German people regarded this stable currency as a miracle because
they had heard such claims of stability before with the Notgeld (emergency
money) that rapidly devalued as an additional source of inflation. The usual
explanation was that the Rentenmarks were issued in a fixed amount and were
backed by hard assets such as agricultural land and industrial assets, but what
happened was more complex than that, as summarized in the following
description.
In August 1923, Karl Helfferich proposed a plan to issue a new currency (Roggenmark) backed by mortgage bonds indexed to market prices (in paper Marks) of rye grain. His plan was rejected because of the greatly fluctuating price of rye in paper Marks. The Agriculture Minister Hans Luther proposed a different plan which substituted gold for rye and a new currency, the Rentenmark, backed by bonds indexed to market prices (in paper Marks) of gold.
The gold bonds were defined at the rate of 2790 gold Marks per kilogram of gold, which was the same definition as the pre-war goldmarks. The rentenmarks were not redeemable in gold, but were only indexed to the gold bonds. This rentenmark plan was adopted in monetary reform decrees on October 13–15, 1923 that set up a new bank, the Rentenbank controlled by Hans Luther who had become the new Finance Minister.
After November 12, 1923, when Hjalmar Schacht became currency commissioner, the Reichsbank, the old central bank, was not allowed to discount any further government Treasury bills, which meant the corresponding issue of paper marks also ceased. Discounting of commercial trade bills was allowed and the amount of Rentenmarks expanded, but the issue was strictly controlled to conform to current commercial and government transactions. The new Rentenbank refused credit to the government and to speculators who were not able to borrow Rentenmarks, because Rentenmarks were not legal tender. When Reichsbank president Rudolf Habenstein died on November 20, 1923, Schacht was appointed president of the Reichsbank. By November 30, 1923, there were 500 million Rentenmarks in circulation, which increased to 1 billion by January 1, 1924, and again to 1.8 billion Rentenmarks by July 1924. Meanwhile, the old paper Marks continued in circulation. The total paper Marks increased to 1.2 sextillion (or 1,200,000,000,000,000,000,000) in July 1924 and continued to fall in value to one third of their conversion value in Rentenmarks.
The monetary law of August 30, 1924 permitted exchange of each old paper 1 trillion Mark note for one new Reichsmark, equivalent in value to one Rentenmark.
Analysis
The
hyperinflation episode in the Weimer Republic in the early 1920s was not the
first hyperinflation, nor was it the first one in Europe, or even the most
extreme—though probably the most famous—instance of inflation in history (the Hungarian
pengo and Zim;babwean dollar have both been even more inflated). However, as
the most prominent case following the emergence of economics as a scholarly
discipline, the Weimar
hyperinflation drew interest in a way that previous instances had not. Many of
the dramatic and unusual economic behaviors now associated with hyperinflation
were first documented systematically in Germany : order-of-magnitude
increases in prices and interest rates, redenomination of the currency,
consumer flight from cash to hard assets, and the rapid expansion of industries
that produced those assets. German monetary economics was then highly
influenced by Chartalism and the German Historical School and this conditioned
the way the hyperinflation was then usually analyzed.
John Maynard Keynes described the situation in The Economic Consequences of the Peace: "The inflationism of the currency systems of
It was during this period of hyperinflation that French and British economic experts began to claim that
Reparations accounted for about one third of the German deficit from 1920 to 1923, and were therefore cited by the German government as one of the main causes of hyperinflation. Other causes cited included bankers and speculators (particularly foreign). The inflation reached its peak by November 1923, but ended when a new currency (the Rentenmark) was introduced. In order to make way for the new currency, banks "turned the marks over to junk dealers by the ton" to be recycled as paper.
No comments:
Post a Comment